Document Type : Research Paper

Authors

1 Professor, Department of Economic Planning and Development, Faculty of Economics, Allameh Tabataba’i University, Tehran, Iran

2 Ph.D. in Economic Development, Department of Economic Planning and Development, Faculty of Economics, Allameh Tabataba’i University, Tehran, Iran

Abstract

Over the past half-century, the impact of the prisoner’s dilemma has transcended its initial boundaries, influencing a broad spectrum of institutional studies and analyses of interdependent systems, such as collective action, public goods, governance of the commons, social norms, and social capital. Given this extensive influence, the latent fundamental flaws in this model can lead to misleading result for researchers and policymakers. As a descriptive–analytical research, the present study employed evolutionary game theory to examine the shortcomings of the iterative and evolutionary prisoner’s dilemma. It went on to introduce an alternative framework to explain the emergence and transformation of institutions. The critical discussion highlighted fundamental deficiencies of the prisoner’s dilemma manifested in four distinct levels of institutional analysis: the definition of institutions, identification of their function, explanation of their emergence, and description of their transformations. Consequently, the model is not capable of explaining institutional issues mentioned above. Addressing the role of uncertainty and considering the impact of small-world networks on payoff distribution, the second part of the study used a semi-parametric stag hunt matrix to model the cooperation problem. The results indicated that the non-spontaneous overlap between strong and weak ties can accumulate synergistic flows between content and structure, creating an environment conducive to institutionalizing capacity for achieving public goods on a large scale. Therefore, the process of overcoming social traps begins not with the punitive rules proposed by the prisoner’s dilemma, but with synergetic institutions that enhance the opportunity to discover common interests.

Introduction

The relation between institutions and development has been well recognized for quite some time. Numerous studies have delved into collective action, public goods, the governance of the commons, informal institutions, social capital, and the like. These areas serve as a common ground between two realms of economics: the theory of institutions and game theory. However, the majority of game theory studies are based on the assumption that the payoff distribution follows the prisoner’s dilemma. In the payoff matrix of the prisoner’s dilemma, the additional benefit of unilateral non-cooperative action results in a dominant strategy, preventing rational players from attaining the mutual benefits of cooperation. The central question in this literature is: how have human beings successfully established society and built civilization? There are three general solutions in the literature on the iterative and evolutionary prisoner’s dilemma. The initial solution, incorporating concepts like meta-game, folk theorem, reputation effect, and the norm of reciprocity, asserts that if the game repeats endlessly, cooperation becomes a foresight-driven choice. Contrary to this approach that suggests a form of spontaneous order, some sociologists argue that negative externalities of individual actions cannot be resolved by foresight or reciprocity, so the evolution of cooperation is only achievable through authoritative relations and punitive norms. The third solution, rooted in a biological assumption, contends that the prisoner’s dilemma can be solved through instincts without the need for rationality. The current article critically examined each of these approaches, and then introduced another payoff distribution matrix to explain how cooperation evolves in human society.

Materials and Methods

This study used a descriptive–analytical method as well as evolutionary game theory.

Results and Discussion

The article can be categorized into two main sections: the critical discussion and modeling. In the critical discussion, the results drawn from agent-based networks indicated that, even in the case of an endlessly repeating game, the emergence of the first cooperators would remain unexplained within the specific payoff matrix. Then, it was demonstrated that a substantial gap between theory and observation arises due to the inadequacy of the Prisoner’s dilemma in representing uncertainty. The discussion also addressed the contradiction stemming from overlooking the institutional context, particularly in defining reciprocity and explaining the emergence of norms. Moreover, the discussion highlighted some tautologies hidden in these definitions and explanations. Finally, three reasons were presented to underscore that the biological approach falls short of explaining how cooperation evolves in small-world networks.
The discussions highlight fundamental deficiencies in the prisoner’s dilemma across four distinct levels of institutional analysis: the definition of institutions, identification of their function, explanation of their emergence, and description of their transformations. At the definitional level, the logic is fundamentally flawed due to its oversight of uncertainty as well as the mere emphasis on non-cooperative payoffs. Concerning the identification of function, the model predominantly stresses control and punishment, neglecting synergetic institutions that enhance opportunities to discover common interests, foster social synthesis on a large scale, lay the foundation for social contracts, and legitimize punitive rules. Moreover, an evolutionary model can only explain the endogenous emergence and transformation of institutions if it first demonstrates how a payoff matrix, where non-cooperation is a dominant strategy, can create a sustainable learning process. According to the results of agent-based networks, such a process cannot be explained in the prisoner’s dilemma.
Nevertheless, evolutionary models, by sidestepping the assumptions of perfect rationality and information, possess a suitable capacity for studying interdependent systems and institutional analysis. Therefore, an alternative model can be formulated by implementing some reforms, including the utilization of the stag hunt matrix to account for uncertainty, incorporating small-world networks to better align with human societies, and ultimately introducing a semi-parametric payoff matrix to incorporate the influences of social structures.
The results from the revised stag hunt model showed that the non-spontaneous overlap between strong and weak ties can accumulate synergistic flows, creating a conducive environment to institutionalizing capacity for achieving public goods on a large scale. Therefore, the process of overcoming social traps begins not with the free ride punishments proposed in the prisoner’s dilemma, but with synergetic institutions that enhance the opportunity to discover common interests.

Conclusion

The prisoner’s dilemma describes a great challenge concerning micro-level conflicts of interest. However, using this model to explain the emergence and transformations of institutions is bound to yield highly misleading results for researchers and policymakers. Instead, the theoretical framework proposed in this study should find application across a broad spectrum of institutional studies, including analyzing the impacts of inclusive institutions on overcoming social traps, designing society-oriented methods for governing the commons, explaining the accumulation and modeling the measurement of social capital, and examining the social consequences of economic inequality.
Keywords: Institutions, Cooperation Problem, Evolutionary Game Theory, Prisoner’s Dilemma, Stag Hunt
JEL Classification: C73, O43.

Keywords

Main Subjects

Aklin, M. & Mildenberger, M. (2020). Prisoners of the wrong dilemma: why distributive conflict, not collective action, characterizes the Politics of Climate Change. Global Environmental Politics, 20(4), 4–27.      https://doi.org/10.1162/glep_a_00578
Alexander, R. D. (1987).  The biology of moral systems. New Jersey: Aldine Transaction.
Alexander, J. (2007).  The structural evolution of morality. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Arnold‏, E. (2014). What's wrong with social simulations?‏ The Monist, 97(3), 359-377. https://doi.org/10.5840/monist201497323
Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books.
Binmore, K. (1992). Fun and games; a text on game theory. Massachusetts: DC Health and Company.
Budescu, D. V., Rapoport, A., & Suleiman, R. (1990). Resource dilemmas with environmental uncertainty and asymmetrical players. European Journal of Social Psychology, 20(6), 475-487.
     https://doi.org/10.1002/ejsp.2420200603
Chavance, R. (2011). Institutional economics. Translated by: Motevasseli, M., Nikoonesbati, A. & Farzizadeh Miandehi, Z., Tehran: Tehran University Press. ]in Persian]
Chu, C., Zhai, Y., Mu, C., Hu, D., Li, T. & Shi‏, L. (2019). Reputation-based popularity promotes cooperation in the spatial prisoner's dilemma game‏. Applied Mathematics and Computation, 362, 124493.      https://doi.org/10.1016/j.amc.2019.06.007
Coleman, J. S. (2011). Foundation of social theory. Translated by: Saboori, M., Tehran: Nashr'e Ney. ]in Persian]
Dawkins, R. (1976). The selfish gene. Oxford: Oxford University Press
Diekert, F., Eymess, T., Luomba, J., & Waichman‏. I. (2020). The creation of social norms under weak institutions‏. Discussion Paper Series, 684, 1-33.     https://doi.org/10.1086/720287
Dugatkin, L. A., Mesterton-Gibbonsand, M. & Houston‏, A. I. (1992). Beyond the prisoner's dilemma: Toward models to discriminate among mechanisms of cooperation in nature. Trends in ecology & evolution, 7(6), 202-205. https://doi.org/10.1016/0169-5347 (92)90074-L
Fleming, L., King, C., & Juda, A. I. (2007). Small worlds and regional innovation. Organization Science, 18(6), 938 -954. 
https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.1070.0289
Friedman, J. W. (1971). A non-cooperative equilibrium for supergames. The Review of Economic Studies, 38(1), 1-12.  
https://doi.org/10.2307/2296617
Fukuyama, F. (2000). Social capital and civil society. IMF working paper, 00/74, 1-19. https://doi.org/10.5089/9781451849585.001
Gilbert, D. R. Jr. (1996). The Prisoner's Dilemma and the Prisoners of the Prisoner's Dilemma. Business Ethics Quarterly, 6(2), 165-178.      https://doi.org/10.2307/3857621
Granovetter, M. (1973). The Strength of weak ties. American Journal of Sociology. 78(6), 1360-1380. https://doi.org/10.1086/225469
Greif‏, A. (1989). Reputation and coalitions in medieval trade: evidence on the Maghribi traders. The Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 857-882.      https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022050700009475
Greif‏, A. (1993). Contract enforceability and economic institutions in early trade: the Maghribi traders' coalition. The American Economic Review, 83(3), 525-548. https://doi.org/10.2307/2117532
Hatch, M. J. (2013). Organization theory: modern, symbolic and postmodern perspective. Translated by: Danaeefard, H., Tehran: Mehraban Pub. ]in Persian]
Hobbes, T. (2001). Leviathan. Translated by: Bashirieh, H., Tehran: Nashr'e Ney. ]in Persian]
Howard, N. (1966). The mathematics of meta-games. General Systems, 11(5), 187-200.
Hu, S. & Leung‏, H. (2018). Do Social Norms Emerge? The Evolution of Agents' Decisions with the Awareness of Social Values under Iterated Prisoner's Dilemma‏. IEEE 12th International Conference on Self-Adaptive and Self-Organizing Systems (SASO), 11-19.
https://doi.org/10.1109/SASO.2018.00012
Kabir, K. A., Tanimoto, J. & Wang, Z.‏ (2018). Influence of bolstering network reciprocity in the evolutionary spatial prisoner’s dilemma game: A perspective‏. The European Physical Journal, 91(12), 1-10.   
https://doi.org/10.1140/epjb/e2018-90214-6
Killingback, T. & Doebeli‏, M. (2002). The continuous prisoner’s dilemma and the evolution of cooperation through reciprocal altruism with variable investment‏. The American Naturalist, 160(4), 421-438. 
https://doi.org/10.1086/342070
Luce, R. P. & Raifa, H. (1957). Games and decisions. New York: John Wiley & Sons.
Marshal, J. A. R., & Rowe. J. E. (2003). Kin selection may inhibit the evolution of reciprocation. Joutnal of Theoretical Biology, 222(8), 331-335. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0022-5193 (03)00039-0
McAdams‏, R. H. (2008). Beyond the prisoners' dilemma: coordination, game theory and law‏. Southern California Law Review. 82, 209-258
Milinski, M. (1987). Tit for tat in sticklebacks and the evolution of cooperation. Nature, 325(6103), 433-435.
https://doi.org/10.1038/325433a0
Motevasseli, M., Samei nasab, M., & Nikoonesbati, A. (2014 a). Institutions and development. Tehran: I.S.U Press. ]in Persian]
Motevasseli, M., Samei nasab, M., & Nikoonesbati, A. (2014 b). Institutionalism and Austrian school: A glance through alternative approaches. Tehran: I.S.U Press. ]in Persian]
Nemeth‏, C. (1972). A critical analysis of research utilizing the prisoner's dilemma paradigm for the study of bargaining. Advances in experimental social psychology. 6, 203-234.
https://doi.org/10.1016/S0065-2601 (08)60028-3
Newman, M. E. J. (2000). Models of the small-world. Journal of Statistical Physics, 101(3), 819–841. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1026485807148
Nolan, P. & Lenski, G. (2012). Human societies; an introduction to macrosociology. Translated by: Movafaqian, N., Tehran: Nashr'e Ney. ]in Persian]
North, D, C., Walis, J. J. & Weingast, B. (2018). Violence and social orders: a conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. Translated by: Kheirkhahan, \J. & Majidzadeh, R., Tehran: Nashr'e Rowzaneh. ]in Persian]
Northcott, R. & Alexandrova, A. (2015). Prisoner's dilemma doesn't explain much‏. Philpapers.org. in Martin Peterson (Ed), The Prisoner’s Dilemma. Classic philosophical arguments. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 64-84.
https://doi.org/10.1017/S0266267116000249
Nowak, M. A. & May, R. M. (1992). Evolutionary games and spatial chaos. Nature, 359(6398), 826–829. https://doi.org/10.1038/359826a0
Nowak, M.A. & Sigmund, K. (1992). Tit for tat in heterogeneous populations. Nature, 355(6457), 250-253.      https://doi.org/10.1038/355250a0
Opotow, S. & Weiss, L. (2000). New ways on thinking about environmentalism: Denial and the process of moral exclusion environmental conflict. Journal of Social Issues, 56(3), 475-490.      https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-4537.00179
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ostrom, E. (2010). Beyond markets and states: polycentric governance of complex economic systems. American Economic Review, 100(3), 641-72.      https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.3.641
Putnam, R. (2013). Making democracy work: civic tradition in modern Italy. Translated by: Delforouz, M. T., Tehran: Jamee Shenasan. ]in Persian]
Raihani, N. J. & Bshari, R. (2011). Resolving the iterated prisoner’s dilemma: theory and reality‏. Journal of Evolutionary Biology, 24(8), 1628-1639. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1420-9101.2011.02307.x
Rawls, J. (1971). A theory of Justice. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Robins, G., Elliott, P. & Pattison, P. (2001). Network models for social selection processes. Social Networks, 23(1), 1–30. 
https://doi.org/10.1016/S0378-8733 (01)00029-6
Robert, K. H. & Broman, G. (2017). Prisoner’s dilemma misleads business and policy makers. Journal of Cleaner Production, 140, 10-16.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.08.069
Rogowski, W. & Lange‏, O. (2022). The prisoner’s dilemma: an adequate concept for ethical analysis in healthcare? a systematic search and critical review. Journal of Business Ethics, 177(5), 1-15. 
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-020-04643-w
Romero, J. & Rosokha‏, Y. (2018). Constructing strategies in the indefinitely repeated prisoner’s dilemma game‏. European Economic Review, 104(C), 185-219. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2018.02.008
Rubinstein, A. (1979).  Equilibrium in supergames with the overtaking criterion. Journal of Economic Theory, 21(1), 1-9.  https:doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531 (79)90002-4
Salzman, P. C. (2015). Understanding culture: an introduction to anthropological theory. Translated by: Kanani, M. A., Tehran: Elmi Farhangi. ]in Persian]
Schilling, M. & Phelps, C. C. (2007). Interfirm collaboration networks: the impact of large-scale network structure on firm innovation. Management Science, 53(7), 1113–1126.
https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1060.0624
Skyrms, B. (2004). The stag hunt and the evolution of social structure. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Snidal‏, D. (1985). Coordination versus prisoners' dilemma: implications for international cooperation and regimes‏. American Political Science Review, 79(4), 923-942. https://doi.org/10.2307/1956241
Sullivan, B. N. & Tang, Y. (2012). Small-world networks, absorptive capacity and firm performance: evidence from the U.S. venture capital industry. International Journal of Strategic Change Management, 4(2), 149–75. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJSCM.2012.046509
Thieme, H. (2005). The lower palaelolithic art of hunting; the case of shoningen I 3 II-4, Lower Saxony, Germany. In Gamble, C. & Porr, M. (Eds): The Hominid Individual in Contex: Archaeological Investigation of Lower and Middle Palaelolithic Landscapes, Locales and Artifacts, 115-132. Landan: Routeledge.
Trivers, R. (1971). The evolution of reciprocal ultruism. The Quarterly Review of Biology, 46(1), 35-57. https://doi.org/10.1086/406755
Tullock‏, G. (1967). The prisoner's dilemma and mutual trust. Ethics, 77(3), 229-230. https://doi.org/10.1086/291638
Ullmann-Margalit, E. (1977). The emergence of norms. Oxford: Oxford University Press
Van Lange, P. A. M., Balliet, D. P., Parks, C. D. & Van Vugt‏, M. (2016). Social dilemmas: the psychology of human cooperation‏. Ttranslated by Javadi yeganeh, M. & Hoseini, H., Tehran: Research Center for Culture, Art and Communication. ]in Persian]
Wang, J., Yu, F., Zhao, J., Li, F. & He‏, J. (2021). How costly altruism survives? The rescue of both cooperation and voluntary sharing‏. Chaos, Solutions & Fractals, 143, 110602.   
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chaos.2020.110602
Wang, J., Wang, R., Yu, F., Wang, Z. & Li‏, Q. (2020). Learning continuous and consistent strategy promotes cooperation in prisoner’s dilemma game with mixed strategy‏. Applied Mathematics and Computation, 370, 124887. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.amc.2019.124887
Watts, D., & Strogatz, S. (1998). Collective dynamics of small world networks, Nature, 393(6684), 440- 442. https://doi.org/10.1038/30918
Wedekind, C., & Milinsky, M. (2000). Cooperation through image scoring in human. Science, 288(5467), 850-852. 
https://doi.org/10.1126/science.288.5467.850
White, L. A. (2015). The evolution of culture: the Development of civilization to fall of Rome. Translated by: Majidi, F., Tehran: Nasl'e Aftab. ]in Persian]
Xiaotong, Q., Siqi, R., & Conglin‏, P. (2021). A study of Institutional Change in Common-pool Resources Governance Model: Based on Reciprocal Altruistic Game Theory‏. 4th International Conference on E-Business, Information Management and Computer Science, 534-539.       https://doi.org/10.1145/3511716.3511797
Yamagishi, T. (1986).  The provision of sanctioning system as a public good. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 50(1), 110-198.      https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.51.1.110